On the heels of the publication by the Center for Medicare
and Medicaid Services (CMS) of how much money Medicare paid to individual
physicians (discussed on this blog in Medicare
payments to doctors: the big issue is the underpayment for primary care,
April 9, 2014), we have revelations of inequity in Federal payments to health providers.
A panel of the National Quality Forum (NQF), convened by the Administration to
look at this issue, has determined that
payments for “quality of care” to hospitals under the Affordable Care Act (ACA)
tend to reward those hospitals caring for higher-income patients and penalize
those who care for the poor (Robert Pear, “Health
law’s pay policy is skewed, panel finds”, New York Times, April 27, 2014). This cannot be the way we want to
go, and thankfully that is the conclusion reached by the panel. It is, however,
the NQF that developed these 600 or so quality indicators, and has not
recommended adjusting them for the socioeconomic status of the patients that a
hospital cares for (although it does adjust for severity of illness).
What is happening is that the measures of quality of care
are largely not measures of what is done for patients in the hospital, but how
they do after – are they readmitted shortly after discharge, are the diseases
for which they are being cared for under better control or not, do they get
follow-up care. The fact is that for a variety of reasons including money, education,
transportation, and competing demands, poor people do not do as well as
better-off people, even controlling for the quality of care that they receive
when they are hospitalized. A number of panel members comment on this in the Times article, including NQF president
Christine Cassel, who says “Factors far
outside the control of a doctor or hospital — patients’ income, housing,
education, even race — can significantly affect patient health, health care and
providers’ performance scores,” and panel member Steven H. Lipstein, CEO of
BJC HealthCare in St. Louis who adds “The administration’s current policy on
adjustments for socioeconomic status are quite inadvertently exacerbating
disparities in access to medical care for poor people who live in isolated
neighborhoods. I’m sure that’s not what President Obama intended with the
Affordable Care Act.”
These comments
are true, but the thrust of the NQF’s comments was the unfairness to the
hospitals. This is important as far as it goes – it is outrageous to pay extra
money for “quality of care” to hospitals that care for the privileged and
penalize those that care for the underserved. Many of the members of the panel
and other commenters quoted by Mr. Pear focus on academic teaching hospitals,
which indeed care for a disproportionate share of poor people; however, public
hospitals (in those areas where they exist) are even more affected. But what is
more important is how this issue illustrates the power of what are called the “social
determinants of health”, the situation that people live in before they access
medical care, and after they are discharged, have on health outcomes.
Health advocate
and policy expert Kip Sullivan is more pointed in his comments on Don McCanne’s
“Quote of
the Day” for April 28, 2014. “The
notion that doctors and hospitals are screwing up and will behave if they are
subjected to punishment and reward by third parties is not new. The Code of
Hammurabi (1750 BC) subjected Mesopotamian doctors to a combination of reward
(more shekels) and punishment (cutting off of doctors' hands)…But even
Hammurabi didn’t recommend punishing the patients.” If hospitals that care for poor people are
effectively financially penalized for doing so, they will (at best) be further
financially challenged in providing that care, and at worst will do their best
to not care for the poor to the extent that they can.
Why would the NQF
and the Department of Health and Human Services (HHS) take such a position, one
that seems both unfair and even mean? One might be tempted to suggest that rewarding
the “haves” and punishing the “have nots” is what is usually done by government
policy, but we would hope that, given its rhetoric on health care – and the
creation of the ACA in the first place – the Obama administration would not be
guilty of such intent. We get some better idea from Kate Goodrich, the director
of quality measurement programs at the federal Centers for Medicare and
Medicaid Services, who is quoted in Mr. Pear’s article as saying “We do not want to hold hospitals to
different standards of care simply because they treat a large number of
low-socioeconomic-status patients. Our position has always been not to
risk-adjust for socioeconomic status within our measures because of concern
about masking disparities, and potentially rewarding providers who provide a
lower level of care for minorities or poor patients.”
Now, this sounds
almost noble, like a values-based response to critics such as those on the NQF’s
panel. However, the clear and obvious flaw in such logic is that hospitals have
the power to change the lives of these patients in such a way as to decrease
their risk for poor outcomes to be equal to, or better, than, those of higher
socioeconomic status. They don’t, and to the extent that they could do more
work in the community to help this situation, it would cost more money, so it
is absurd that they be financially penalized. Dollars spent by government on
health care should first and foremost be required to be spent on health, not on
making money for providers (doctors or hospitals) who can by virtue of their
location (and possibly other strategies) avoid taking care of the neediest.
Hospitals should be judged and reimbursed on the quality of care that they
deliver, equitably and without prejudice with regard to socioeconomic status,
but cannot reasonably be judged on outcomes which depend on factors far outside
the control of those hospitals.
The real issue is
that people who are poor have a lot more to contend with than the services
delivered as health care. It is not uncommon for our hospital to be treating a
person with a bone infection made worse by their diabetes who needs 6 weeks of
IV antibiotics. This can be delivered by a home health care agency, and most
insurance will pay for it. But it becomes a problem if the person does not have
insurance. And is even more complicated when they do not have a home. These
people stay in the hospital, at exorbitant cost, for the whole duration of
treatment. But would our quality measures be better if we only cared for those
with homes and insurance? Would the hospital make more? Of course, as Mr.
Sullivan points out, while the hospitals lose financially, ultimately it is the
patients who suffer.
The social
determinants of health are well-portrayed in the “cliff analogy” developed by
Dr. Camara Jones and her colleagues,[1]
and discussed in my blog of September 12, 2010, “Social
Determinants, Personal Responsibility, and Health System Outcomes”. The care given by hospitals occurs at
the bottom of the cliff, after people have fallen, but their risk, both before
arriving at the hospital and in returning home, is that they are living so
close to the cliff face; their housing is poor, their neighborhoods are
dangerous and polluted, their schools do not educate, and food is often scarce
and not nutritious. In their study
comparing health costs in the US and Europe, Elizabeth Bradley and colleagues
discovered that while the US spends far more on “health care”, if you add in
basic social service spending, the difference decreases, but that the US spends
most of its combined health-and-social-service spending on medical care.[2]
(Discussed in a New York Times
op-ed, “To
fix health care, help the poor” by Bradley and Lauren Taylor, and in my
blog “To
improve health the US must spend more on social services”, November 18,
2011.)
It is understandable that, given the political climate in
Washington and state capitals and the flak that they took for ACA, the Obama administration
does not want to put major effort into addressing the social determinants of
health by developing programs to meet the core needs of poor people in our
country, to prevent them from getting sick, to give them access to meaningful
post-hospital care, to have health workers in communities, punish polluters,
decrease crime, and limit health risks. Understandable, but not OK. And in the
meantime, on this narrower issue, it obviously requires adjusting for
socioeconomic risks for hospitals caring for the poor when their quality
incentive payments are calculated.
But sometime soon we are going to have to address the core
problems.
[1] Jones
CP, Jones CY, Perry GS, “Addressing the social determinants of children’s
health: a cliff analogy”, Journal of
Health Care for the Poor and Underserved, 2009Nov;20(4):supplement pp 1-12.
DOI: 10.1353/hpu.0.0228. Slides available on line at http://www.csg.org/knowledgecenter/docs/health/CamaraJones.pdf.
[2] Bradley
EH, Elkins BR, Herrin J, Elbel B.,Health and social services expenditures:
associations with health outcomes, BMJ Qual Saf. 2011 Oct;20(10):826-31. Epub
2011 Mar 29
I am a rising medical student and hope to one day incorporate social medicine into my practice and treatment philosophy. I've recently read the book about Paul Farmer's work, Mountains Beyond Mountains, and many of your points are reiterated in his theories about the social aspects of health care distribution. It appears that the US system of healthcare was not designed with the poor in mind, and until we develop a medical system that looks at patients from a more comprehensive and holistic perspective, we will continue to utilize our healthcare system as a symbolic system that maintains an imbalanced power structure. Great read!
ReplyDelete