We know that health care in the US is incredibly expensive. Those
who read about health policy from a variety of sources (perhaps including this
blog) know this in terms of data – our per capita cost is 50% more than the
second highest-cost nation (Norway), twice what most comparable (rich)
countries spend, and almost 3 times that of the United Kingdom. But you don’t
have to be a policy wonk to know that health care is expensive; you just have
to be a consumer who is trying to buy health insurance and is seeing their
premiums go up – and their out-of-pocket costs (deductibles, co-pays,
co-insurance) go up as well. All those other countries cover everyone,
equitably, despite spending so much less money (and those that spend more, like
Norway, have especially good coverage). Not so here.
“My premiums are more
than $600 a month, which is more than our mortgage payment,” a cancer
survivor quoted by the New York Times
in its August 14, 2016 article by Robert Pear “Health
insurers use process intended to curb rate increases to justify them”, said. “I am grateful that the Affordable Care
Act is here for my family, but I am disappointed by its limitations. All I want
is a plan that makes our health care affordable, but it doesn’t exist.” She
is likely to be disappointed, because this was not how the Affordable Care Act
(ACA) was set up, and unless control of Congress changes dramatically, we
probably will not see a fix. ACA passed because it guaranteed continued profit
for insurance companies, and this has led to both the rate increases and
out-of-pocket cost increases we have seen. Insurance companies can do this
because the law allows them to ask for premium hikes when they are not making
“enough” money. Essentially, ACA requires the American people (subsidized by
the federal government if they are poor) to ensure private insurance companies
are profitable. Because they believe that they have not been permitted to jack up
rates “enough”, some companies (Humana, United, Ætna) are leaving the exchanges in many places.
While other counties make sure everyone is covered by some
national health insurance (a national health service in the UK, a single-payer
national health insurance system in Canada, and highly-regulated multi-payer
systems in many other European countries such as France, Germany, and
Switzerland), we have tried a patchwork that leaves many people out (e.g., the
undocumented, poor people in the 19 states that haven’t expanded Medicaid),
and encourages others to buy policies on the health insurance exchanges based
solely on their cost. This is examined in a story by Reed Abelson in the Times from August 12, 2016, “Cost,
not choice, is top concern of health insurance customers”. It notes that
people who are healthy and young but don’t have employer-based health insurance are either buying the cheapest
policies available on the exchanges or “particularly those not
eligible for generous subsidies, are shunning plans altogether, finding all of
the prices too high.” When they don't buy insurance, it messes with the insurance company model of
offsetting costs for sick people with the premiums paid by healthy people, the
reason for increasing premiums. And many other people, neither young nor
healthy, are also buying the cheapest policy they can find because they can’t
afford the cost (and maybe can’t understand the details); for these folks, it
is not the insurance companies that pay the financial price, but themselves, when
they get hospitalized or otherwise need costly care and discover that their
“insurance” is inadequate (the technical term here is “crap”).
And this is just the health insurance contribution to high health care cost. Also very important is the cost
of the care itself, particularly high-tech, high-cost care, provided to many Americans
(at least those with good insurance coverage). This is driven, at least
currently, by the fact that in most places, where insurance companies pay providers by piecework (“fee-for-service”), high-cost is also high-profit for providers,
both individual physicians and the large institutional providers (hospitals and
health systems) that often employ them. This blog, and a variety of exposés in
many news articles including in the Times
(particularly the work of Elisabeth Rosenthal) have given example after
example of such incentives driving both the kind of care delivered and the cost
of that care. In the worst instances, this is the result of rapacious greed that provides
unnecessary care at very high cost. In many other settings, the opportunity for
profit subtly (I hope) tips the scales toward providing high-cost, high-profit
services rather than just as good, or almost as good, alternatives. But there
are even more insidious drivers of cost; these are in the “everyday tests”, such
as those done for screening, that in themselves, one by one, don’t seem to be
excessive but multiplied by the number of people receiving them cost a lot (and
make a lot of money for providers). The practice of ordering such tests is
often driven by advocacy groups, providers in certain specialties and
relatively small numbers of people with a specific condition who think everyone needs to be tested for it.
A good example is screening for lipid disorders (basically, high
cholesterol) in children. Yes, some children have a genetic disorder which
means that they should be tested and treated, but the vast majority do not and screening them (barring a history of familial hyperlipidemia or very early heart
attacks) should not be done. It is not recommended by either the US
Preventive Services Task Force or the American Academy of Family Physicians
(AAFP), nor by the UK National Screening Committee. This example is discussed
in an outstanding editorial in JAMA
Internal Medicine by Thomas B. Newman, Alan R. Schroeder, and Mark J.
Pletcher published on August 9, 2016, titled “Lipid
screening in children: Low-value care”, preceded by the tagline “Less is more.”
The authors contrast the USPSTF and AAFP recommendations to those of the
National Heart, Lung and Blood Institute of the NIH, endorsed by the American
Academy of Pediatrics, which recommends it. The authors of the editorial
demonstrate the amazing lack of cost-effectiveness for this screening test, and
note that is only because USPSTF does not consider cost-effectiveness that it
gave the test an “I” (insufficient evidence to recommend for or against”) and
not a “D” (recommend against testing).
But the most important point made in the editorial is that
our recommendations for testing – and how to spend our healthcare dollars – are
individually focused, and virtually ignore (and thus dramatically underfund)
those interventions in public health and the social determinants of health that
would truly make a major difference in the health of millions of Americans. The
authors say it extremely well:
Tackling
major public health concerns such as climate change, poverty, obesity, and gun
violence is likely to yield high-value solutions, and many advocate policy and
community-level interventions that might achieve such solutions. Meanwhile,
other segments of our health care establishment continue to try to solve health
problems by doubling down on individual-level health care solutions that tend
to be low in value...The need for clinicians and leaders to focus on
sustainability and health care value has never been greater, and it is likely
that policy and community-based interventions will get us there much more quickly
than adding more clinic-based interventions that have low value and are
wasteful of resources and clinicians’ time.
We need to take this advice to heart. It goes way beyond
lipid screening in children. It means supporting interventions that actually improve the health of the public on a large scale. And, as always, “support” is
spelled M-O-N-E-Y.
I llke your blog a lot, but you made a quaint comment when you said that the ACA was designed to guarantee the profits of insurance companies.
ReplyDeleteActually the insurers have lost billions of dollars since 2013, and that is why many of them are bailing out of the program.
The problem is more complex than insurer profits.
Is there really evidence that they have "lost billions of dollars", or just that they are not making as much as they hoped and want to? Of course, we understand the fact that you need a lot of healthy people paying premiums to balance out the costly sick, and the higher prices on the exchanges and low penalties mean not everyone is buying them. But while it may have been an overstatement to say that ACA "guaranteed the profits", the individual mandate, and the absence of a public option, and the absence of pricing limits, certainly dealt the insurers a fine opening hand.
ReplyDelete