Elisabeth Rosenthal, the editor-in-chief of Kaiser Health
News and author of “An American Sickness” (discussed in this blog on April 15,
2017, United
Airlines, health care, and a system designed to privilege the powerful) has
an op-ed in her old newspaper, the New
York Times, on May 29, 2017 titled “We
all have pre-existing conditions”. That is a good and accurate title, but a
little different from the print title “The cost of pre-existing conditions”. That cost is high, to the
people with those conditions, and less obviously, to the overall society. This
includes their families and friends, of course, but also their employers. When
a potentially treatable condition excludes you from having health insurance,
you are less likely to get it treated, and more likely to get sick and miss
work. The spectrum of conditions that insurance companies used in the pre-ACA
era to exclude people was broad. Rosenthal notes specific examples including having had an abnormal Pap smear, a history of being on anti-depressants, a
history of taking thyroid medication, and being on post-menopausal hormone
treatment. Of course, once you are excluded and have no insurance, you don’t
seek care for other conditions either, either pre-existing or those that develop later or
might have not been recognized. Not only could insurers exclude you for having
a pre-existing condition, but there was no regulation of what or how
significant that condition had to be. We have heard stories of people being
denied treatment for cancer because, on signing up, they had “failed to report”
a pre-existing history of treatment for things as minor as an ingrown toenail
or acne!
The ACA, also known as Obamacare, changed that. It
eliminated the ability of insurance companies to exclude people based on their
pre-existing conditions, thus rendering moot the question of what conditions
could be excluded. It also prevented those insurance companies from charging
more money to people with those pre-existing conditions by requiring “community
rating”; they had to set their rates based upon the overall actuarial risk of
the entire community in which they sell insurance. The same principle is why
those of us who receive our health insurance via employers, especially large
employers, usually have lower rates for better coverage – because the risk pool
is everyone who works for that company, and while many are sick, many more are
younger and healthier (after all, this excludes all the people who are not
working). Thus, the requirement that the individual policies sold under ACA had
to be based on the community rating was critical for many Americans to be able
to get even close to affordable health insurance.
For many, the cost on the individual marketplace was still
too high. For those whose pre-existing conditions had previously made them
unable to get insurance, it was often still a boon. For those who were younger
and healthier, though, who had had cheaper policies or gone without coverage
altogether, they now had to pay more. After all, community rating means an
average, so those at lower risk will pay more than they would have with
individual rating, and certainly more than with no insurance since the ACA had
the “individual mandate” requiring them to get coverage. The bigger problem is
that in some geographic areas, many (or most or in some cases all) insurers
decided that the benefit of offering insurance (i.e., making money) was not
worth the risk of paying out for actual medical care. This is especially true
in rural areas, where low population density and a higher proportion of older
and therefore sicker people make for a poor risk/return ratio.
The problem, of course, for those younger and healthier
people who chose to forgo coverage or, after the individual mandate, to buy
the cheapest and crappiest policies, is that they can get sick. They can discover
that they have cancer, whatever their age. Or get into a car accident,
requiring many surgeries and long treatment and rehabilitation (did they have
car insurance?). Or be burned in a fire started by smoking (did they have
homeowner’s insurance? Did they opt to not pay the higher premiums that they
can legally be charged for being smokers?) Or they can have a premature baby
that needs treatment in a neonatal ICU. Or,
particularly for the older group who knew they had a problem like hypertension,
diabetes, or arthritis but were hoping they’d stay relatively asymptomatic,
they can have a downturn – have a stroke or a heart attack or a serious
infection or pain so bad that they can no longer work. And then they find that
the “affordable” (i.e., crappy) health insurance that they bought is almost as
bad as none.
So we have a conundrum. To work, health insurance has to
include everyone, the sick as well as the healthy. But the healthy, especially
those with lower incomes, don’t want to pay what seems to be the unfairly high
rates that they have to in order for the whole system to be fair. The older and
less healthy may want health insurance, but still be dissuaded by the high
premiums. The sick need the coverage, but again, without the healthier paying
in, the cost for them is too high, and results in either their being unable to afford
it or the insurers being unwilling to cover them even if it means leaving an
entire market.
Let’s look at some facts:
1. The US spends more on health care than any other county, by far.
2. The US has, on a population basis, worse health outcomes than most other developed countries, far worse than many.
1. The US spends more on health care than any other county, by far.
2. The US has, on a population basis, worse health outcomes than most other developed countries, far worse than many.
This is the true conundrum. How can we pay so much for so
little? It is because we pay an enormous percent of our “health care” expenses for drug company (and
drug “middlemen”, pharmacy benefits managers) profits, insurance
company profits, and income for for-profit and function-like-for-profit
non-profit hospitals. As documented by Eric Lipton and Katie Thomas in the May
29, 2017 Times (“Drug
lobbyists’ battle cry over prices: blame the others”), there is plenty of blame to go around! In addition, the percent that
is actually spent on health care on treatments (and sometimes cures) is primarily for far
advanced disease, not prevention and early diagnosis and treatment. We spend
almost nothing on public health and prevention.
We keep telling ourselves lies (our healthcare system is the
best in the world, the ACA is the problem, drug companies need to charge so
much because they spend so much on research and development, etc.) but fewer
and fewer of us are believing it. Many of the people who are worst affected
voted for Donald Trump and for Republican congressmen who have devised the AHCA
(American Health Care Act) that will “solve” the problem by essentially
eliminating health insurance coverage for 23 million Americans, 14 million in
the first year alone, according to estimates by the non-partisan Congressional
Budget Office (CBO). The AHCA is
basically a tax-cut-for-the-1% bill, with the money coming from the health care
coverage for the rest of us.
Is there any way out of this conundrum? Yes. We have the
money, obviously; we are spending it. Fifty percent of health care spending is
already government, 60% if you include the lost taxes from the employer portion
of health insurance. We make the community being rated everyone in the US. We all have one health plan. We are all
covered. We all get all necessary services. We don’t lose coverage by leaving
or jobs for any reason, from family needs to an entrepreneurial start-up. The
old and vulnerable among us are covered and have their needs met, and the
healthy among us win by staying healthy and having coverage when we need it. We
pay for it by eliminating the profit centers, and not by cutting taxes on the
wealthiest of us.
It can be done. It has been done. In every other developed
country. We have the resources to do it here. We must need to stand up to the
entrenched and powerful profiteers.
No comments:
Post a Comment