It’s not easy to be a big healthcare system these days, what
with all the new rules and incentives for spending less money and providing
less unnecessary care. Medicare is leading this charge, with a variety of
efforts, mostly recently contained in the 2015 Medicare Access and CHIP
Reauthorization Act, fondly known as MACRA. This law extends previous efforts
by Medicare to encourage consolidation and “shared savings” (spend less and you
get to keep some) through the creation of “alternative payment models” (APMs),
most of which emphasize increasing prospective payment (paying in advance for a
basket of services to be delivered to a population) rather than fee-for-service
(paying for each service provided).
In some ways, and particularly in some places, such large
health systems are well-positioned for these changes; because they are big and
provide the whole range of healthcare services (or most of it), and because many
of them employ physicians, they should be able to take advantage of the
efficiencies of scale, as well as understand their comprehensive costs. Many of
them are; Kaiser, especially on the West Coast, and other early-adopters of
this comprehensive model. Other payers are following Medicare’s lead, such as
Blue Cross/Blue Shield of Massachusetts.
Still, it’s hard to change your business model. When your
health system has been designed for decades to maximize income from
fee-for-service by hiring lots of specialists who provide services (often
procedures) that bring in a lot of money and supplying them with the expensive
facilities and equipment to do them, it is scary to think that this entire
investment could move from being a profit center to a cost center, where each
of these procedures just chips off money already received in capitation rather
than generating new revenue. Plus APMs create incentives to spend less overall,
and you have spent decades gearing up to spend more – with the expectation and
assumption that reimbursement would more than cover this investment.
And if you are not on a coast, but in the
part of the country where such changes are happening more slowly, and in fact
are mostly still in the future and you’re still making money the old way, it is
a very scary and risky proposition to change your business model completely. The
analogy of when it is time to put your second foot in a canoe is an apt one.
The dock is a stable place to be, comfortable and familiar, but the canoe can
take you off to new, and maybe wonderful, places. But there is only a limited
amount of time that you can keep one foot on the dock and one in the canoe
before the canoe moves off and you end up falling in the lake.
One of the big concerns confronting such health systems is
the degree to which they should invest in expanding primary care capacity. The
argument for doing so, put forward by most consultants and experts, is that it
ensures a patient base loyal to their system and referring in to their
hospital(s) and specialists and providing a more comprehensive ability to
manage the spectrum of care. The other option is to “double down” and be
providers of only high-end, high-cost (and hopefully high-profit) care, with
the assumption that the community’s primary and secondary care providers will
see you as a beacon for their complex problems and refer their patients to you. This latter
position is especially popular among academic medical centers, hospitals tied
to a medical school and a faculty practice group, and is much closer to the
advice given by the University Health Consortium, the organization of such
hospitals.
Along with this is the question of how income might be
distributed. Most of the incentives in MACRA and prospective payment are for
primary care; in addition to direct reimbursements for primary care providers,
the shared savings come from a higher percent of conditions being managed by
primary care and not subspecialists, fewer hospitalizations resulting from
greater continuity of care, and fewer referrals for imaging (x-rays and the
like) of questionable necessity but easy availability (because the capacity for
doing them has been overbuilt). Kocher and Chigurupati discuss these issues in
their July 14 piece in the New England
Journal of Medicine, “The Coming Battle over Shared Savings — Primary Care: Physicians versus Specialists”.[1]
The main point of the piece is how specialty physicians will respond to their
incomes decreasing – they suggest the options are defensive (fight it and keep
doing what they are doing) or offensive (sell themselves as more able to
contain costs especially for certain disease conditions). Of course, what works
for some specialists may harm others; if, say, a pulmonologist caring for
chronic obstructive lung disease is very efficient and their patients need less
imaging and fewer admissions, it can hurt others.
The average American is not going to have great sympathy for
loss of income for such specialists. The authors cite the mean income for
primary care doctors as $195,000, about 4 times the average US household
income, and average for specialists $284,000, significantly more but deceptive
in that many specialist make 2, 3, or more times that. Thus a $35,000 reduction
in income, which is what the authors use in their example, is likely to mostly
concern these doctors. The authors also note that primary care physicians
“…account directly for a small percentage of health care costs. Yet they
substantially influence the total cost of care through referrals and directing
of their patients’ subsequent care.” They are, or could be, cost effective,
provided that there is not pressure from the system to increase referrals –
something that has usually been the norm, and even touted by primary care
physician groups who talk about “downstream revenue” generated.
Of course, nowhere in these discussions is the question of
what is best for the health of the American people. Implicitly, MACRA and the
ACA before it (with its creation of accountable care organizations or ACOs),
are intended to increase both access to care and its quality (two legs of the
“triple aim”), but arguably have been put forward by both the federal government
(Medicare) and adopted by other insurers to achieve the third leg – lower cost.
And for insurers, including Medicare, the concern is lower cost to them. The issues addressed heretofore
in this piece and by Kocher and Chigurupati and by consultants such as the
Advisory Board and organizations like UHS, are how healthcare providers (healthcare
systems, academic and otherwise, physicians and other individual providers) can
most effectively respond to keep from losing money, from having the cost
savings for insurers come at a big cost to
them.
The health of the people should be the measure. And it needs
to be the health of all the people, the poorest and sickest and most vulnerable
and most easily left off, not just the high-yield, high-profit generally
healthy, well-insured person who needs a single procedure and has no
complicating conditions. Indirect incentives that seek to modify behavior by
not demanding that all necessary health needs be provided to all people and no
unnecessary care be provided to anyone are all bound to fail. Societies are, or
should be judged, not by how they care for their most privileged but by how they care for their
most needy (see the FDR epigram at the top right of this page).
And nowhere is this more true than when it comes to the
people’s health.
[1] Kocher R, Chigurupati A, The Coming Battle over Shared
Savings — Primary Care Physicians versus Specialists, NEJM 375(2):104-106,
July
14, 2016
2 comments:
In the struggle to change the payment system, academic health centers and medical schools are in the worst position to do so - entrenched belief systems about "value" and prestige will get in the way of logic and, just as the last time around with HMO's and capitation, there will be "research" to prove what medical schools inherently believe - so that the status quo can be supported. Go back and read Jared Diamond's Collapse if you want an insight into what is likely to happen to academic health centers - cutting down the last tree on Easter Island
Hi Josh,
I loved your illustration of the person with one foot on the dock and one on the canoe, as the system changes from fee-for-service to some kind of prospective payment. When I've discussed this issue, I've used the image (often seen in the cartoons of my youth) of someone who is suddenly caught in an earthquake, and the ground cracks open beneath him, and keeps getting wider and wider. He has one foot on either side of this growing chasm, and just keeps looking back and forth in a panic trying to decide which side to jump toward.
I like your illustration better! Don
Post a Comment